Beyond Embeddedness: Economic Sociology as a Historical Theory of Society

Interview with Jens Beckert

Jens Beckert is a central figure among the second generation of economic sociologists who emerged following the discipline’s revival in the 80’s and the pioneering work of Mark S. Granovetter, Harrison White, Paul DiMaggio, Viviana Zelizer, Frank Dobbin, Richard Swedberg, and Neil Fligstein. Over the last twenty years his work has greatly contributed to the institutionalization of economic sociology in Europe. Since 2005 Beckert has been the director of the Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies (MPIfG), one of the leading research institutes for economic sociology and political economy. Beckert is currently one of the central theorists working in economic sociology.

The interview was conducted by
Felipe González López, Universidad Central de Chile, and
Marcin Serafin, Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies, Instytut Filozofii i Socjologii PAN

Published in: Studia Socjologiczne 226 (3): 239–56, 2017.

 

Felipe González and Marcin Serafin: For those less familiar with your work, could you describe the trajectory of your academic career? How did you become interested in economic sociology? How have your interests developed over the years?

Jens Beckert: From the beginning of my university studies I was very interested in issues related to the economy. I started studying sociology in the late 1980s at the Freie Universität Berlin and took several courses in the fields of organization studies, industrial sociology, and industrial relations.

It is worth mentioning that the 1980s was a time when the last waves of interest in Marxist sociology were quite visible at the Freie Universität (this changed after the collapse of the Berlin Wall). I also studied business administration as a second major. My interest in economic phenomena became even more pronounced at the beginning of the 1990s when I went to The New School in New York. I read there some of the literature on socio-economics and in the emerging field of what became later known as the new economic sociology. I became interested in Amitai Etzioni's book “The Moral Dimension” (Etzioni 1988) and I read for the first time works by Mark S. Granovetter and Viviana Zelizer (Granovetter 1985; Zelizer 1988).

You must remember that, although this work was already being published in the 1980s, there was not yet a field called “new economic sociology”; the field was still in the process of formation. What was important to me were the readers that came out at this time, many of them edited by Richard Swedberg (Smelser and Swedberg 1994; Swedberg 1990; Swedberg and Granovetter 1992). Later I spent a year at Princeton while writing my dissertation. In the mid-90s Princeton was the center of economic sociology with scholars such as Paul DiMaggio, Viviana Zelizer, Frank Dobbin and Bruce Western teaching there.

FP, MS: In the programmatic statement “What is sociological about economic sociology?” (Beckert 1996b) you argued that the theoretical foundations of economic sociology must be found in the concept of uncertainty and a theory of economic action. Why do you see uncertainty as the central concept for economic sociology?

JB: For me a crucial question has always been “why should there be an economic sociology at all?” Intuitively one can say that within the social sciences there exists the field of economics which studies the economy, so why should sociologists study this topic as well? There is a need to define an entrance point for economic sociology, and I believe that the most promising entrance point is the problem of uncertainty. What I mean by uncertainty is the notion of radical or fundamental uncertainty.

If one goes back to the distinction made by Frank Knight between risk and uncertainty (Knight 2002), radical uncertainty is the situation in which you cannot calculate probabilities for future outcomes. If you take this problem seriously, then the question opens up how actors, who are intentionally rational, make choices if they cannot calculate optimal decisions. If one investigates economic decisions under uncertainty, bringing in sociology becomes unavoidable. This provides justification for why understanding the economy and intentionally rational action needs a sociological contribution.

I have developed this problem further in an article entitled “The social order of markets”, where I state that the problem of uncertainty can be analyzed in the form of different coordination problems, which I call the problems of valuation, competition, and cooperation (Beckert 2009). If you look carefully at the literature that has emerged over the last twenty-five years in economic sociology, quite a few authors used the concept of uncertainty, some explicitly others implicitly.

»Economic sociology needs a systematic starting point, it needs to proceed from a theoretical problem. Uncertainty is such an issue.«

Explicitly it is used for instance in the work of Akos Rona-Tas on credit cards (Guseva and Rona-Tas 2001), or the work of Joel Podolny (2001). More implicitly one finds it in the works of Harrison White (2002). For White the question of coordination of actors in the economy is how stable reproducible role structures in markets can emerge (White 1981). This needs to happen to reduce uncertainty. I would still maintain today that the concept of uncertainty provides a fundamental theoretical starting point for economic sociology. Economic sociology needs a systematic starting point, it needs to proceed from a theoretical problem. Uncertainty is such an issue.

FP, MS: The problem that you mention about fundamental uncertainty is also the problem of how social order is possible, which you frame in the sociological concept of double contingency. Parsons and Luhmann also started from this particular problem but they developed it in the form of a system theory. You on the other hand suggest that this problem must be addressed with an action theory. Why do you see action theory as the starting point for a theoretical foundation of economic sociology?

JB: The observation is certainly right. In my dissertation Talcott Parsons and Niklas Luhmann are two of the authors I have dealt with in detail. When I was writing the article on uncertainty, both authors were an important influence. However, I was always interested in action theory. This is in part also because I learnt from studying economics that it is crucial for the explanation of outcomes to have a micro-foundation. One needs to explain how macro-phenomena relate to micro-interactions. This doesn't mean that all unintended consequences or macro phenomena can be reduced to agency, but it is necessary for a sociological theory to make the contribution of agency to social outcomes intelligible.

In the early Talcott Parsons you find the very same intuition. With regard to Luhmann it is true that his work was very much influenced by phenomenology and his early theory had a foundation in action theory.

FP, MS: We can see in your work references to classical and contemporary authors coming from a variety of sociological traditions and levels of analysis, such as system theory, field theory, network analysis, and pragmatism. How do you integrate these different backgrounds into your work? To what extent have they influenced your development as an economic sociologist?

JB: I have never defined myself as a Weberian, Durkheimian or Bourdieusian, “applying” the work of one of these “grand” authors. Instead, I take a much more pragmatic attitude toward theories. I am attentive to concepts that will help me understand the problems that interest me. Certainly what brings the different influences together is a strong interest in action theory. This includes the question how action is shaped by social structures, such as institutions, networks and cultural frames, and how actors interpret a situation.

»I have never defined myself as a Weberian, Durkheimian or Bourdieusian. Instead, I take a much more pragmatic attitude toward theories.«

There is also a normative strand which is important for my work and this is where the pragmatist part comes out more strongly. I never believed in a sociology in which actors are seen as being determined by social structures. Of course, the social environment of actors has an influence on how they act. But what interests me is how, through the interpretation of the situation, actors shape their environment in contingent ways. It is this interaction between structures and agency that I find thought-provoking and I make use of concepts and theories which are of help to conceptualize this issue.

FP, MS: In your most recent work (Beckert 2013a; 2013b; 2016) you conceptualize this relationship between structures and agency in the economy by introducing the concept of “fictional expectations”. Could you tell us about this development in your theory and how it relates to your previous work on uncertainty?

JB: This relates quite closely to the issue of structure and agency. In the article from 1996 I argued that actors rely on “social devices” to cope with the problem of uncertainty. Today I believe that this underestimates the role of agency in the economy. Actors faced with complex decisions develop imaginaries of how their future will look like before they take a specific decision. In an investment decision, for instance, the entrepreneur “experiences” the outcome in imagination before the first dollar has been spent.

Under conditions of uncertainty, however, it is impossible to understand these expectations as rational in the sense that they would foreshadow an actual future present. Instead the expectations create a world of their own. In this sense I speak of “fictional expectations”. Expectations are relevant for decisions and at the same time they are contingent or undetermined – they could always be different. This opens also an important avenue for a core political understanding of decision making in the economy. Actors are interested to influence the expectations of others. Competition is largely about the deliberate shaping of the expectations prevailing in the field.

FP, MS: At the Max Planck Institute you have been working with Wolfgang Streeck in bringing economic sociology and political economy closer together (Beckert and Streeck 2008). Could you tell us more about this project?

JB: I think that for economic sociology this is one of the most exciting paths to pursue. When I came to the Max Planck Institute in 2005, I started working with Wolfgang Streeck, a sociologist with a strong background in political economy. His interests focus more on macro-phenomena, looking at the interaction between macro-outcomes and institutional structures (Streeck 2009; Streeck 2012). His work stands in the tradition of historical institutionalism. So you see the combination: he is looking from macro-phenomena to the institutional level and I am looking from the micro-level to the institutional level. At the same time we are both investigating economic phenomena in their social contexts.

»If we want to understand economic dynamics it is crucial to include social developments writ large.«

What I see as a fundamental problem for quite a bit of work in the new economic sociology is that it doesn't include the macro level. If we want to understand economic dynamics it is crucial to include social developments writ large. Research projects in economic sociology should be organized more around the question of how capitalism as a social and economic system is operating, how it is changing, and what social dynamics it creates. The stronger connection to political economy could bring economic sociology out of a situation where many very interesting case studies have been conducted without demonstrating how this knowledge helps us understanding general economic and social developments. The strong interaction with political economists that we develop at the Max Planck Institute is an incredible opportunity for the further development of the field.

What is economic and sociological about economic sociology?

FP, MS: An important division of labour between economics and sociology was established by Talcott Parsons – economists dealt with means-ends and scarcity, while sociology dealt with values. To a great extent the revival of economic sociology implied a break with these boundaries. After almost thirty years of accumulated research and debates within economic sociology, how do you see its relationship with economics?

JB: One first needs to say that neither economics, nor economic sociology exists as a monolithic block. It means the relationship between these two fields depends on which economics and which economic sociology we are talking about. So for instance I would say that the network approach in economic sociology connects quite easily to mainstream economics; indeed, many economists have taken up network studies from sociology.

If I try to answer the question from the perspective of the kind of economic sociology that I am interested in, the relation with mainstream economics is a complicated one. Economic sociology is much less interested in abstract model building based on non-realistic assumptions and tries instead to understand economic phenomena based on empirical observations. Mainstream economics operates on the basis of rational choice theory.

In my work I attempt to pursue an alternative to this. One may argue that the relationship with behavioral economics is easier, but this is true only in a limited way. It is true in the sense that behavioral economics shares the conviction that actors do not always act rationally. But the findings from behavioral economics are in most cases trivial. That norms of fairness play a role in economic interactions is something that sociologist have known for at least a hundred years and is hardly news.

»As a sociologist I want to explain social facts with social facts and not with psychological facts.«

Behavioral economics is also unsatisfying from a sociological perspective because it explains deviations from the rational actor model by referring to psychological factors which are ultimately traceable to the hardwired structures of our brain. As a sociologist I want to explain social facts with social facts and not with psychological facts. I think that the relation between economics and economic sociology will remain very distant as long as economists refrain from placing more emphasis on the social forces operating in the economy and turn away from a sociologically meaningful theory of action.

FP, MS: In your view, what defines the economic sociology? In your work you deal a lot with markets. Would you say economic sociology is the sociology of markets?

JB: Certainly in my work markets stand out as a dominant topic. I believe that this is justified because markets are simply the most important institutions of contemporary capitalist economies. But this does not mean that economic sociology should be limited to the sociology of markets. Economic sociology has always had a very strong affinity to organization studies. The investigation into firms is a crucial field in economic sociology. Indeed one cannot understand markets without understanding firms. Nevertheless I maintain that markets should be the vantage point for understanding capitalist economies, because firms need to orient their decisions and structures towards their opportunities on markets.

There are clearly also other very interesting topics. One of them that interests me – even though I have never worked on it – is reciprocity. There is quite a lot of highly interesting work in the Maussean tradition. This work is partly related to markets, but most importantly it shows that there are other forms of allocation of goods even in modern societies. Of course house-holding would be another example where the economic dimension of non-market forms of exchange comes prominently into play.

As a last point, coming back to political economy, I would say that it is crucial for economic sociology to conceptualize the relationship between markets and the state. The state is the most central institution regulating markets, and no understanding of contemporary economies is possible without understanding the role of the state. This is the case in parts of economic sociology, for instance, in the works of Neil Fligstein (2002), Greta Krippner (2011), Frank Dobbin (1997), or Bruce Carruthers (1999), but nevertheless economic sociologists need to be reminded again and again of the significance of the state and the operation of the political system for the explanation of economic outcomes.

FP, MS: Economic sociology has been a particularly productive sub-discipline of sociology and many of the scholars working within this field have made important contributions to organization studies, the sociology of knowledge, field theory, sociological institutionalism, and cultural sociology. What do you think about the relationship between economic sociology and general sociology? What has sociology gained from economic sociology?

JB: Let me start with answering the question the other way around. Economic sociology is part of the sociological enterprise which means that concepts developed in sociology are applied to the study of the economy. This also holds true for the methods used in economic sociology. Having said this, the discipline of sociology, I think, can learn from economic sociology about one important part of society.

But I would also say that economic sociology does not emphasize enough the significance of the analysis of the economy for understanding social dynamics in a broader sense. If we think of our society as a capitalist society, this implies that the dynamics of it have to a large extent to do with the dynamics of the economic system. Economic globalization, competition in markets and the operation of the financial system have profound effects on societies: processes of dislocation, changes in demography, changing family structures, new mobility demands on actors, and structures of social inequality.

»Economic sociology has the potential to aim much higher and develop a theory of society.«

Based on its knowledge of the economy, economic sociology has the potential to aim much higher and develop a theory of society. Unfortunately, few economic sociologists are thinking in this direction. The danger of not doing so is that economic sociology will become a subfield for people interested in the economy but will certainly contribute little to our understanding of societal dynamics. This however should be the project of sociology.

Contemporary debates in economic sociology

FP, MS: Regarding debates within economic sociology, in October 2012 there was a joint ASA and ESA conference in Moscow. You, together with Patrik Aspers, were responsible for a section on “New theoretical perspectives in economic sociology”. What do you see as the main current trends and the main debates within economic sociology today?

JB: Quite a bit of very good work has been produced on financial markets in recent years. This work has been largely motivated by the financial crises of 2007 and 2008. This is an important topic and, since the financial crises will stay with us in one way or another, it is a topic that will remain important. The current work on finance and financialization is also most closely related to political economy.

Other important topics relate to the issue of uncertainty and the three coordination problems I have already mentioned. There is a great deal of interest concerning the valuation of goods, questions of price formation, and how quality categories are established in markets. These are issues where a long tradition of sociological knowledge can be applied very fruitfully to economic phenomena. Scholars such as Marion Fourcade (2011) or David Stark (2011) are doing fantastic work in this field. The same holds true for a number of scholars in France. The subject of confidence and trust – it stands behind what I call the problem of cooperation – plays a crucial role in the operation of financial markets and the monetary system. Again, there is also excellent work on this topic.

Furthermore, the performativity approach certainly remains important even twenty years after the first papers on it have been published (Callon 1998; MacKenzie, Muniesa and Siu 2007; MacKenzie and Millo 2003). It is part of a cognitive turn in economic sociology. There is one additional topic I want to mention although it plays no more than a marginal role in economic sociology today. This concerns the issue of illegal markets.

»We cannot understand the development of the legal part of the economy without having an understanding of its illegal counterpart and the relation between the two.«

I find it remarkable that there is hardly any work in economic sociology on illegal markets (Beckert and Dewey 2017). Work is available on the informal economy, but even this work has a more marginal role. Almost all research in economic sociology proceeds from the assumption that the interactions taking place in the economy are legal, although we know that this is simply not the case. In many ways we cannot understand the development of the legal part of the economy without having an understanding of its illegal counterpart and the relation between the two. Uncharted territory exists here for economic sociologists, which should be explored. The sociology of finance, for instance, would be a more interesting field of study if it paid more attention to illegal activities in financial markets and to the question of how powerful actors attempt to exploit grey zones between legality and illegality.

FP, MS: Since the revival of economic sociology the notion of embeddedness has been one of its central (if not the core) concepts, but at the same time it has been understood in different ways. The debate seems to go back to different readings of Karl Polanyi. One way of reading Polanyi is the “always embedded” approach, for which the economy is always embedded in social relations and the role of economic sociology is to study thems.

This is clearly characterized in the work done e.g. by Viviana Zelizer (2010). The other – we can call it the “double movement” reading of Polanyi – argues that a self-regulated market system becomes disembedded and destroys the social foundations on which it has been built, and characterizes more the work of political economists. You have written extensively on the notion of embeddedness (Beckert 1996, 2003, 2006). How do you see the concept and how do you read Polanyi? Is it necessary to go “beyond embeddedness”?

JB: The concept of embeddedness has been crucial for defining economic sociology. One does not have to call it embeddedness, but in the end the approach is about the social contexts shaping economic action. For me this is also what the broad notion of embeddedness entails.

If one looks at the development of the new economic sociology, especially in the United States, the understanding of embeddedness has often been a much narrower one. This goes back to the article by Granovetter (1985), where embeddedness is associated with the network approach. This is an understanding of embeddedness which does not do justice to Polanyi.

One way ahead is to simply broaden the concept. This has been suggested many years ago by Sharon Zukin and Paul DiMaggio (1990). They distinguish between different versions of embeddedness: political embeddedness, cognitive embeddedness, cultural embeddedness, and structural embeddedness. In this view networks are only one type of embeddedness. I would say one should always consider the different forms of embeddedness when explaining economic action.

But then there is a more principled point to which you alluded by referring to the idea that the economy is “always embedded”. There is no economy that can operate without, for example, institutional structures. To have competitive markets you need anti-trust laws to keep competition open. A law is an institution and can be defined as an expression of institutional embeddedness. But what Polanyi had in mind is not embeddedness in this sense.

»It becomes possible to see embeddedness as a variable where markets can be either more curtailed or more organized as free markets.«

He is rather talking about the limitation of the free market. This, however, brings us to a much more historical and also dynamic view of the concept. It becomes possible to see embeddedness as a variable where markets can be either more curtailed or more organized as free markets. Based on this understanding of embeddedness, one can ask questions such as: In what historical periods are markets more or less embedded? Why is this the case? How do these developments come about and what consequences for social development emerge from them?

Such a perspective aims much more towards a historical theory of society. This is a theory which understands current configurations of the economy from the historical trajectories in which they have developed and the political struggles from which economic configurations emerge. It is by understanding economic configurations, not out of an efficiency logic, as mainstream economics or institutional economics does, but from political and cultural struggles.

I find this much more appealing than to simply state that networks or institutions are important for the operation of contemporary economies. It also shows that embeddedness, in the Polanyian sense, is not something that we can simply take for granted. Instead it can vanish. In the end it is a political project to embed the economy in a way that it is compatible with social developments that are normatively desirable.

FP, MS: So for you it is more than just the idea of protecting capitalism from itself?

JB: This is of course one element of it, but it is only the economic dimension. This would be a functionalist perspective. What I mean beyond this is that embeddedness points also to the potentially destructive forces that derive from unfettered markets. This is a normative project in the sense that economic development cannot be reduced to economic efficiency but that we need to reflect also upon criteria of social justice and concepts of “the good life” which should inform the regulation, or the embeddedness, of the economy.

FP, MS: Focusing more on the normative aspect of economic sociology, there has recently been much debate about the need for a “public sociology”. This debate, started by Michael Burawoy, has also reached economic sociology (Swedberg et al. 2007). Do you think economic sociology should play a public role?

JB: Yes, but this applies not just to economic sociology, but also to sociology as such. Sociology is a discipline which has its roots in the Enlightenment. One crucial idea of enlightenment thinking is to inform people – by knowledge gained from science – about the social forces which operate in a society and which influence their lives. The hope is that this will help people to be more able to influence the social structures to which they are subject.

»We need an economic sociology which is interested not only in understanding of how economic exchange depends on social structures, but also in how these structures emerge and change in political struggles and how societies are influenced by the dynamics of the economy.«

If you look at the development of sociology over the last thirty years you can see a diminution of the public role of sociology. The current economic and political crisis opens up an opportunity for sociologists to regain a more prominent public role. I claim they can do this mainly by investigating the economy. For a more public role of sociology, economic sociology is crucial because the organization of the economy is so central to all other spheres of social life.

However, to play a public role, we need an economic sociology in the sense that I sketch it: interested not only in understanding of how economic exchange depends on social structures, but also in how these structures emerge and change in political struggles and how societies are influenced by the dynamics of the economy. I wish that economic sociologists would understand this more clearly.

FP, MS: Would you say that your work on inheritance law represents this type of public sociology (Beckert 2008)? Why do you see inheritance as a public issue?

JB: Inheritance is an important topic because the bequest of wealth from one generation to another is a crucial instrument through which social inequality is perpetuated. There are also other institutions which have this effect, especially educational institutions, but inheritance is the most direct institution of reproducing inequality intergenerationally.

It is striking that sociologists are paying so little attention to this topic. To answer your question more directly: I observe that journalists and political groups with very different political orientations become quite interested in the topic of inheritance. This is because the question of how to regulate the bequest of property is a pertinent social and political issue.

What I try to do when I talk to journalists is to somehow – using Albert Hirschman's (1984) word – “complicate” the discourse. I try to make a contribution to inform the public debate that is often based on fears and lack of information. In this sense this work is intended to also play an enlightening role.

Bibliography

  • Aspers, Patrik. 2011. Markets. Cambridge: Polity Press.
  • Beckert, Jens. 1996a. “Was ist soziologisch an der Wirtschaftssoziologie? Ungewißheit und die Einbettung wirtschaftlichen Handelns.” Zeitschrift für Soziologie 25: 125–46.
  • Beckert, Jens. 1996b. “What is sociological about economic sociology? Uncertainty and the embeddedness of economic action.” Theory and Society 25(6): 803–40.
  • Beckert, Jens. 1997. Grenzen des Marktes: Die sozialen Grundlagen wirtschaftlicher Effizienz. Frankfurt a.M.: Campus: Reihe Theorie und Gesellschaft.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2002. Beyond the market: The social foundations of economic efficiency. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2003. “Economic sociology and embeddedness: How shall we conceptualize economic action?” Journal of Economic Issues 37(3): 769–87.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2004. Unverdientes Vermögen: Soziologie des Erbrechts. Frankfurt a.M.: Campus Verlag.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2006. “Trust and markets.” In: Handbook of trust resarch, edited by Reinhard Bachmann and Akbar Zaheer. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 318–31.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2008. Inherited wealth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2009. “The social order of markets.” Theory and Society 38(3): 245–69.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2010a. “How do fields change? The interrelations of institutions, networks, and cognition in the dynamics of markets.” Organization Studies 31(5): 605–27.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2010b. “Institutional isomorphism revisited: Convergence and divergence in institutional change.” Sociological Theory 28(2): 150–66.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2011a. “The transcending power of goods.” In: The worth of goods: Valuation and pricing in the economy, edited by Jens Beckert and Patrik Aspers. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 106–31.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2011b. “Where do prices come from? Sociological approaches to price formation.” Socio-Economic Review (9)4: 757–86.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2013a. “Capitalism as a system of expectations toward a sociological microfoundation of political economy.” Politics & Society 41(3): 323–50.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2013b. “Imagined futures: Fictional expectations in the economy.” Theory and Society. 42(3): 1–22.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2015. “Fictional expectations and capitalist dynamics.” In: Re-imagining economic sociology, edited by Patrik Aspers and Nigel Dodd. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 55–78.
  • Beckert, Jens. 2016. Imagined futures: Fictional Expectations and Capitalist Dynamics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
  • Beckert, Jens, and Patrik Aspers. 2011. The worth of goods valuation and pricing in the economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Beckert, Jens, and David Dequech. 2006. “Risk and Uncertainty.” In: International encyclopedia of economic sociology, edited by Jens Beckert and Milan Zafirovski. London: Routledge, pp. 582–587.
  • Beckert, Jens, and Matías Dewey (Eds.). 2017. The architecture of illegal markets. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Beckert, Jens, and Christine Musselin. 2013. Constructing quality: The classification of goods in markets. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Beckert, Jens, and Wolfgang Streeck. 2008. Economic sociology and political economy a programmatic perspective. Cologne: Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies.
  • Bourdieu, Pierre. 2005. The social structures of the economy. Cambridge: Polity Press.
  • Callon, Michel. 1998. The laws of the markets. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.
  • Callon, Michel. 2008. “Economic markets and the rise of interactive agencements: From prosthetic agencies to habilitated agencies.” In: Living in a material world: Economic sociology meets science and technology studies, edited by Trevor Pinch and Richard Swedberg. Cambridge: Cambridge MIT Press, pp. 29–56.
  • Carruthers, Bruce G. 1999. City of capital: Politics and markets in the English financial revolution. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Deutschmann, Christoph. 2011. “A pragmatist theory of capitalism.” Socio-Economic Review 9(1): 83–106.
  • Dobbin, Frank. 1997. Forging industrial policy: The United States, Britain, and France in the railway age. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Etzioni, Amitai. 1988. The moral dimension: Toward a New Economics. New York: Free Press.
  • Fligstein, Neil. 1996. “Markets as politics: A political-cultural approach to market institutions.” American Sociological Review 61(4): 656–73.
  • Fligstein, Neil. 2002. The architecture of markets: An economic sociology of twenty-first-century capitalist societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Fourcade, Marion. 2007. “Theories of markets and theories of society.” American Behavioral Scientist 50(8): 1015–34.
  • Fourcade, Marion. 2011. “Cents and sensibility: Economic valuation and the nature of 'nature'.” American Journal of Sociology 116(6): 1721–77.
  • Fourcade, Marion, and Kieran Healy. 2007. “Moral views of market society.” Annual Review of Sociology 33(1): 285–311.
  • Granovetter, Mark S. 1985. “Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology 91(3): 481–510.
  • Guseva, Alya, and Akos Rona-Tas. 2001. “Uncertainty, risk, and trust: Russian and American credit card markets compared.” American Sociological Review 66(5): 623–46.
  • Healy, Kieran. 2006. Last best gifts: Altruism and the market for human blood and organs. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  • Hirschman, Albert. 1984. “Against parsimony: Three easy ways of complicating some categories of economic discourse.” The American Economic Review 74(2): 89–96.
  • Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2008. “Markets.” In: The new Palgrave dictionary of economics, edited by Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Joas, Hans, and Jens Beckert. 2001. “Action theory””. In: Handbook of sociological theory, edited by Jonathan H. Turner. New York: Springer US, pp. 269–85.
  • Joas, Hans, and Wolfgang Knöbl. 2009. Social theory: Twenty introductory lectures. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Knight, Frank Hyneman. 2002. Risk, uncertainty and profit. Washington, DC: Beard Books.
  • Krippner, Greta R. 2011. Capitalizing on crisis. Harvard: Harvard University Press.
  • MacKenzie, Donald A., Fabian Muniesa, and Lucia Siu. 2007. Do economists make markets? On the performativity of economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • MacKenzie, Donald, and Yuval Millo. 2003. “Constructing a market, performing theory: The historical sociology of a financial derivatives exchange.” American Journal of Sociology 109(1): 107–45.
  • Podolny, Joel M. 2001. “Networks as the Pipes and Prisms of the Market.” American Journal of Sociology 107(1): 33–60.
  • Rössel, Jörg, and Jens Beckert. 2012. “Quality classifications in competition price formation in the German wine market.” MPIfG Discussion Paper. Cologne: Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies.
  • Sewell, William H. 2008. “The temporalities of capitalism.” Socio-Economic Review 6(3): 517–37.
  • Simon, Herbert Alexander. 1982. Models of bounded rationality: Empirically grounded economic reason. Cambridge: MIT Press.
  • Smelser, Neil J., and Richard Swedberg. 1994. The handbook of economic sociology. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Stark, David. 2011. The sense of dissonance: Accounts of worth in economic life. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Streeck, Wolfgang. 2009. “Institutions in history: Bringing capitalism back in.” Cologne: Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies.
  • Streeck, Wolfgang. 2011. “E pluribus unum? The varieties of capitalism.” In: Sociology of economic life, edited by Mark S. Granovetter and Richard Swedberg. Boston: Westview Press, pp. 419–455.
  • Streeck, Wolfgang. 2012. “How to study contemporary capitalism?” European Journal of Sociology / Archives Européennes de Sociologie 53(01): 1–28.
  • Swedberg, Richard. 1990. Economics and sociology: Redefining their boundaries. Conversations with economists and sociologists. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Swedberg, Richard. 1994. “Markets as social structures.” In: The handbook of economic sociology, edited by Richard Swedberg and Neil Smelser. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 255–83.
  • Swedberg, Richard, Fred Block, Akos Rona-Tas, Nadav Gabay, and Michael Burawoy. 2007. “Economic sociology as public sociology.” Socio-Economic Review 5(2): 319–67.
  • Swedberg, Richard, and Mark S. Granovetter. 1992. The sociology of economic life. Colorado: Westview Press.
  • White, Harrison. 1981. “Where do markets come from?” American Journal of Sociology 87(3): 517–47.
  • White, Harrison. 2002. Markets from networks: Socioeconomic models of production. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Zelizer, Viviana. 1988. Beyond the polemics on the market: Establishing a theoretical and empirical agenda. Sociological Forum 3(4), 614–634.
  • Zelizer, Viviana. 2010. Economic lives: How culture shapes the economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Zukin, Sharon, and Paul DiMaggio. 1990. Structures of capital: The social organization of the economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

 

Project Area Sociology of Markets

Markets as the core institution of capitalist economies are the focus of the project area “Sociology of Markets.” The overarching aim is to understand the functioning of markets from a distinctively sociological perspective. Markets are analyzed from a Weberian viewpoint as arenas of social struggle in which actors confront each other under conditions of competition. What are the social, cultural, and political underpinnings for the development of the order of markets? One crucial vantage point of the research projects is the problem of uncertainty market actors face when making decisions. This, in turn, sheds light on the coordination problems market participants must cope with, which can very abstractly be summarized as the problem of value, the problem of competition, and the problem of cooperation. Uncertainty also provides a theoretical opening to explain the embeddedness of economic action. In recent years, the project area has focused increasingly on the role of perceptions of the future in economic decision-making and in explaining economic outcomes.

Other Interesting Articles

Go to Editor View